MAKING SOCIAL SECURITY PROGRESSIVE

MAKING SOCIAL SECURITY PROGRESSIVE

Social Security is funded by a regressive tax in which wages below the wage cap ($160,200 in 2023) are taxed at a flat rate but wages above the cap are taxed at zero. To address this normative shortcoming and make Social Security progressive, this Piece proposes eliminating the wage cap and using the resulting additional revenue to fund a zero-rate Social Security tax bracket analogous to the standard deduction of the federal income tax.

IRS data show that these changes could fund an exemption of at least $10,000, thereby saving low-wage taxpayers approximately $1,200. By altering only the distribution of the tax burden, but not the total revenue collected or Social Security benefits, these changes would also be straightforward to implement.

These changes would be especially valuable for millions of impoverished low-wage earners for whom the additional funds would provide much-needed support, and for certain racial groups whose decreased life expectancy reduces their total Social Security benefits.

The full text of this Piece can be found by clicking the PDF link to the left.

Introduction

Social Security, the largest social safety-net program in the United States, 1 At more than $1 trillion annually, Social Security spending represents approximately 5% of gross domestic product. CBO, The 2022 Long-Term Budget Outlook 7 (2022), https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2022-07/57971-LTBO.pdf [https://perma.cc/​7C7S-GK2M]. is funded by a 12.4% flat tax on wages capped at $160,200. 2 Contribution and Benefit Base, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/cbb.html [https://perma.cc/NY2B-LQBE] [hereinafter SSA, Contribution and Benefit Base] (last visited Jan. 24, 2024). Social Security taxes are paid half by the employee and half by the employer (6.2% each), but there is general agreement that the incidence of both portions is borne by the employee. See CBO, Historical Effective Federal Tax Rates: 1979 to 2004, at 3 (2006), https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/109th-congress-2005-2006/reports/​EffectiveTaxRates2006.pdf [https://perma.cc/RN7Z-6K4G] [hereinafter CBO, Effective Federal Tax Rates] (“CBO assumes—as do most economists—that employers’ share of payroll taxes is passed on to employees in the form of lower wages than would otherwise be paid.”); Staff of Joint Comm. on Tax’n, 107th Cong., Overview of Present Law and Economic Analysis Relating to Marginal Tax Rates and the President’s Individual Income Tax Rate Proposals 47–48 (2001), https://www.jct.gov/getattachment/a67e5594-7702-4c34-b313-b49ced6ac79a/x-6-01-2078.pdf [https://perma.cc/XJ53-QH7W] (“[M]ost analysts conclude that both the employee’s and employer’s share of the payroll tax is borne by the employee and that therefore the marginal payroll tax rate would include both the employee’s and employer’s share.”). Because earnings above this wage cap are exempt from tax, Social Security tax collection is regressive, with low-wage taxpayers paying a higher average tax rate on their wages relative to taxpayers with wages exceeding this threshold. 3 This usage of “regressive” refers to a tax system in which the average tax rate decreases as the taxable base increases. See Manoj Viswanathan, Retheorizing Progressive Taxation, 75 Tax L. Rev. 91, 100 (2021) (“[T]he most common definitions of progressive taxation express tax burden as a percentage of some stated base . . . .”). This leads to peculiar outcomes: As salaries exceed the wage cap, the Social Security tax rate decreases and approaches zero. 4 In 2023, taxpayers with $10 million and $160,200 of wages (the 2023 wage cap) would both pay $19,865 in Social Security taxes (12.4% × $160,200 = $19,865). But the taxpayer with $10 million of wages would pay a Social Security tax rate of 0.2% ($19,865 ÷ $10 million = 0.2%), whereas the taxpayer with $160,200 of wages would pay a Social Security tax rate of 12.4%.

To address this normative shortcoming, this Piece proposes eliminating the wage cap and using the resulting additional revenue to fund a zero-rate Social Security tax bracket analogous to the standard deduction of the federal income tax. IRS data show that eliminating the wage cap could fund an exemption of at least $10,000, thereby making Social Security tax collection progressive across all wage earners. By altering only the distribution of the tax burden but not the total revenue collected or the Social Security benefits, these changes would also be straightforward to implement. This benefit-neutral and revenue-neutral change to Social Security would be especially valuable for the millions of impoverished low-wage earners for whom the additional funds would provide much-needed support and for certain racial groups whose decreased life expectancy reduces their total Social Security benefits. 5 See Ariel Jurow Kleiman, Impoverishment by Taxation, 170 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1451, 1462–64 (2022) (discussing how payment of taxes, including payroll taxes, pushes millions of taxpayers further into poverty); infra section III.C.3.

Part I of this Piece provides an overview of Social Security. Part II discusses Social Security’s regressivity and explains why Social Security tax collection and benefit provision should both be progressive. Part III discusses the proposal’s particulars, namely, eliminating the wage cap for Social Security taxes and using the revenue generated to create a zero-rate Social Security tax bracket.

I. Social Security: An Overview

The Social Security program was launched in 1935 in response to the hardships caused by the Great Depression, with its best-known benefit providing payments to retirees aged sixty-five and older. 6 Karen M. Tani, Welfare and Rights Before the Movement: Rights as a Language of the State, 122 Yale L.J. 314, 325 (2012) (“The Social Security Act of 1935 [was] best known for initiating a national system of old-age insurance . . . .”). The Act also provided for unemployment insurance, aid to dependent children, and state grants for certain medical care. Historical Background and Development of Social Security, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/history/briefhistory3.html [https://perma.cc/X3HB-D8SS] (last visited Jan. 24, 2024). Although the program has evolved since its inception, several original features remain, including compulsory participation, calculation of benefits as a function of payments, and financing of benefits from payroll taxes levied on employees and employers. 7 See Martha A. McSteen, Fifty Years of Social Security, Soc. Sec. Bull., Aug. 1985, at 36 (describing development of Social Security policy and administration between 1935 and 1985). Today, Social Security provides monthly benefits to about 66 million people, making annual payments in excess of $1.2 trillion. 8 SSA, Summary: Actuarial Status of the Social Security Trust Funds 1–2 (2023), https://www.ssa.gov/policy/trust-funds-summary.pdf [https://perma.cc/Z9KA-MKRD] [hereinafter SSA, Trust Funds Summary].

Taxes on wages fund Social Security benefits. 9 See infra note 14 and accompanying text; see also SSA, Annual Statistical Supplement to the Social Security Bulletin, 2023, at 7 (2023), https://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/statcomps/supplement/2023/supplement23.pdf [https://perma.cc/E2X8-MHMZ] [hereinafter SSA, 2023 Annual Statistical Supplement]. Federal taxes on wages have many names, including payroll taxes and employment taxes. See, e.g., Stephanie Hunter McMahon, Employment Taxes in Crisis: In Practice, Enforcement, and Insolvency, 75 Tax Law. 187, 189 (2021) (using both terms interchangeably when discussing federal taxes). This Piece uses the term “Social Security taxes” to refer to the wage tax revenue funding the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (OASDI) trust fund. Employers and employ­ees together pay 12.4% of the first $160,200 10 SSA, 2023 Annual Statistical Supplement, supra note 9, at 8. in salary, primarily to two separate trust funds: Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) and Disability Insurance (DI). 11 Id. at 7; see also Jonathan Barry Forman & Gordon D. Mackenzie, Optimal Rules for Defined Contribution Plans: What Can We Learn From the U.S. and Australian Pension Systems?, 66 Tax Law. 613, 617 (2013) (“The Social Security system includes two major programs that provide monthly cash benefits to workers and their families.”). Most economists (and the CBO) assume that employees bear the burden of the employer-paid portion of OASDI contributions as well. See CBO, Effective Federal Tax Rates supra note 2, at 3. OASI benefits retired workers and their dependents; DI benefits disabled workers and their dependents. 12 Forman & Mackenzie, supra note 11, at 617. Together, these two trust funds and their associated benefits comprise what is collo­quially known as Social Security. 13 Id. Moreover, all wages are subject to a 2.9% tax (1.45% both for employers and employees). 2023 Annual Statistical Supplement, supra note 9, at 8, 4.41 n.d. This tax revenue goes into the Hospital Insurance (HI) trust fund, a core component of the Medicare program. See id.; see also Bd. of Tr., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2022 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds, H.R. Doc. No. 117-126, at 1 (2022) (“[Medicare] has two separate trust funds, the Hospital Insurance trust fund (HI) and the Supplementary Medical Insurance trust fund (SMI).”). Although they are technically separate entities, they are commonly presented as one fund for actuarial purposes: the OASDI. 14 Benjamin A. Templin, Social Security Reform: The Politics of the Payroll Tax, 32 Quinnipiac L. Rev. 1, 4 (2013). The SSA assumes transferability between the two trust funds when determining long-term solvency for the combined OASDI trust fund. See, e.g., Bd. of Tr., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2023 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 3 (2023), https://www.ssa.gov/OACT/TR/2023/​tr2023.pdf [https://perma.cc/X74M-WMLH] [hereinafter 2023 Annual Report] (“OASDI cost is projected to exceed total income in 2023, and the dollar level of the hypothetical combined trust fund reserves declines until reserves become depleted in 2034 . . . .”).

Social Security differs from most other federal spending programs in that payments for beneficiaries come from the OASDI trust fund, not the federal government’s general funds. 15 Bill Heniff Jr., Cong. Rsch. Serv., Basic Federal Budgeting Terminology 2 (2012), https://www.budget.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Basic%20Federal%20Budget%20Terminology1.pdf [https://perma.cc/R4Y2-KU9T] (“Currently, there are three accounts designated in law as off-budget: the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance Trust Fund (Social Security retirement), the Federal Disability Insurance Trust Fund (Social Security disability), and the Postal Service Fund.”). Congress is obligated to make payments to beneficiaries and is precluded from using OASDI funds for any other purpose. 16 See 42 U.S.C. § 401(h) (2018) (“Benefit payments required to be made . . . shall be made only from the Federal Disability Insurance Trust Fund . . . [or] Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance Trust Fund.”); What Are the Trust Funds?, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/news/press/factsheets/WhatAreTheTrust.htm [https://perma.cc/CU99-X729] (last visited Jan. 24, 2024) (“The only purposes for which these trust funds can be used are to pay benefits and program administrative costs.”). Social Security is thus protected from the congressional scavenging to which general funds might be vulnerable. Social Security taxes paid by current wage earners go directly into the trust fund, and later to the current beneficiaries. 17 Regina T. Jefferson, Privatization: Not the Answer for Social Security Reform, 58 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 1287, 1294 (2001) (“[T]he system immediately uses the contributions of current workers to finance the benefits of current retirees.”). OASDI surpluses are loaned to the federal government in exchange for bonds, which are then sold as needed to pay beneficiaries. See Barry F. Huston, Cong. Rsch. Serv., RL33028, Social Security: The Trust Funds 1, https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/RL/RL33028 [https://perma.cc/​3WPE-RRNY] (last updated May 16, 2023). See infra section III.C.2 for a discussion on the long-term solvency of Social Security.

Benefit payments to retirees comprise the lion’s share of OASDI payouts. 18 The 2022 payouts from OASI and DI were $1.088 trillion and $144 billion, respectively. See SSA, Trust Funds Summary, supra note 8, at 2. Thus, more than 88% ($1.088 trillion ÷ ($1.088 trillion + $144 billion) = 88.3%) of OASDI payments were for retirement benefits. These payouts are calculated by reference to average indexed monthly earnings (AIME), an inflation-adjusted measure of a worker’s average income during the thirty-five years of their highest earnings. 19 See SSA, Annual Statistical Supplement to the Social Security Bulletin, 2021, at 11 (2021), https://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/statcomps/supplement/2021/​supplement21.pdf [https://perma.cc/29AL-U9TC]. If a retiree has fewer than thirty-five years of earnings, years with zero earnings are added to the calculation. Id. The income credited for any given year is capped at the wage cap in place for that year. 20 See SSA, Contribution and Benefit Base, supra note 2; see also Benefit Calculation Examples for Workers Retiring in 2024, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/oact/ProgData/​retirebenefit1.html [https://perma.cc/KB53-UTZN] (last visited Nov. 2, 2023). The SSA’s method of calculating a retiree’s monthly Social Security benefit weights higher AIMEs proportionately less than lower AIMEs. 21 Assuming normal retirement age, a retiree’s monthly benefit (known as their primary insurance amount or PIA) is calculated by adding the following three values: 90% of AIME up to a first threshold (known as the first bend point), 32% of AIME between the first and second bend point, and 15% of AIME greater than the second bend point. See Primary Insurance Account, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/piaformula.html [https://perma.cc/JC3S-Y952] (last visited Nov. 2, 2023). In 2024, the first and second bend points are $1,174 and $7,078, respectively. Id. Retiring earlier reduces the monthly benefit; retiring later increases the monthly benefit. Early or Late Retirement?, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/oact/quickcalc/early_late.html [https://perma.cc/BN6R-6ZVL] (last visited Nov. 2, 2023). Even though a higher AIME always results in a higher total Social Security benefit, the Social Security benefit as a percentage of AIME decreases as AIME increases. Thus, Social Security benefits (in contrast to Social Security taxes collected) are progressive, with monthly benefits as a percentage of AIME decreasing as wages increase. 22 A worker with the maximum creditable earnings retiring in 2020 at the normal retirement age of sixty-six will obtain approximately $3,600 a month in 2024. Workers with Maximum-Taxable Earnings, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/examplemax.html [https://perma.cc/H7CS-X9SK] (last visited Nov. 2, 2023). Benefits are indexed annually for inflation. Cost-of-Living Adjustments, SSA, https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/​colaseries.html [https://perma.cc/7YF4-YESP] (last visited Jan. 24, 2024).

Although Social Security benefits are progressive (with respect to AIME) for beneficiaries, this is not sufficient to ensure progressivity of the Social Security program in the aggregate. The following Part describes how Social Security is markedly more regressive if assessed by income and explains how progressivity of benefits is not sufficient to counteract the regressivity of Social Security tax collection.

I. The Regressivity of Social Security Taxes

A. Social Security Tax Collection

Taxpayers with wages above the Social Security wage cap pay a lower average Social Security tax rate than taxpayers with earnings below the wage cap. 23 See supra note 3 and accompanying text. Because wages above the cap are exempt from tax (that is, there is a zero marginal Social Security tax rate imposed on wages above the cap), the average Social Security tax rate imposed on these earners will necessarily be less than the average rate imposed on earners with wages below the cap. A lawyer earning a salary of $300,000 is taxed at approximately half the rate of a nurse earning $100,000, 24 The lawyer in this example would owe $19,865 (12.4% × $160,200 = $19,865) in social security taxes on their $300,000 salary, for an effective tax rate of 6.6% ($19,865 ÷ $300,000 = 6.6%). The nurse, on the other hand, would owe $12,400 (12.4% × $100,000 = $12,400), for an effective tax rate of 12.4% ($12,400 ÷ $100,000 = 12.4%). while a college football coach earning $10 million pays a social security tax rate of approximately 0%. 25 $19,865 ÷ $10 million = 0.2%. Even though the lawyer and the football coach have the same Social Security tax liability as measured in total dollars—$19,865—this fixed liability represents a decreasing percentage of wages as wages increase.

Progressivity assessments of Social Security often use wages as both the taxable base and the distributional yardstick by which the tax burden is compared. 26 See, e.g., Andrew G. Biggs, Mark Sarney & Christopher R. Tamborini, A Progressivity Index for Social Security 1 (2009), https://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/​issuepapers/ip2009-01.pdf [https://perma.cc/N95Y-CBL9] (“The progressivity index compares the distribution of the present value of lifetime benefits to the distribution of the present value of lifetime taxes.”). Because the tax burden (expressed as a percent of wages) decreases as wages increase beyond the wage cap, Social Security taxes can be considered regressive. This analysis compares taxpayers using wages, but if regressivity were measured with reference to income, the distributional shortcomings of Social Security tax collection become even more pronounced and Social Security taxes would be significantly more regressive. Because high-wage earners also tend to have other sources of income, such as capital gains and other returns from investment, the percentage of income paid in Social Security taxes for these high-wage earners is generally much lower than the percentage of wages. 27 CBO, The Distribution of Household Income, 2018, at 7 (2021), https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2021-08/57061-Distribution-Household-Income.pdf [https://perma.cc/P5WR-UFPF] [hereinafter CBO, Distribution of Household Income]. Using a progressivity base different from the base for which tax burdens are collected is not uncommon. Soda taxes and sales taxes, for instance, though nominally flat, are routinely described as regressive when assessed using income (rather than ounces of soda or amount purchased) as the progressivity base. See, e.g., Katherine Pratt, A Constructive Critique of Public Health Arguments for Antiobesity Soda Taxes and Food Taxes, 87 Tul. L. Rev. 73, 122–23 (2012) (“Soda tax and food tax proposals raise distributional concerns because such taxes would be regressive, meaning that the taxes would constitute a higher percentage of a poor person’s income than a wealthy person’s income.”); Robert H. Gleason, Comment, Reevaluating the California Sales Tax: Exemptions, Equity, Effectiveness, and the Need for a Broader Base, 33 San Diego L. Rev. 1681, 1714 (1996) (“The most common criticism [of] . . . a sales tax [is that it] is regressive, that is, it bears more heavily on poorer taxpayers because the overall rate of taxation increases less rapidly than the increase in tax base (here, income) . . . .”). For low-wage earners, wages and total income are essentially identical. 28 See CBO, Distribution of Household Income, supra note 27, at 7.

Thus, to the extent income (as opposed to wages) is a better measure of a taxpayer’s ability to pay and therefore a better metric by which to assess progressivity, the current Social Security tax rate structure is even more regressive than generally considered. If the lawyer from the preceding example has $100,000 in capital gains, for instance, the Social Security tax rate as a percent of income drops from 6.6% to 5.0%. 29 If the lawyer has capital gains of $100,000, they have $400,000 of gross income ($300,000 in wages and $100,000 in capital gains). Thus, Social Security tax liability as a percentage of gross income is 5.0% ($19,865 ÷ $400,000 = 5.0%). See also supra note 24 (calculating the lawyer’s effective tax liability for a gross income of $300,000).

B. Social Security Benefits

Social Security’s benefit formula, as described in Part I, credits the first dollars of a worker’s earnings at a much higher percentage than their last dollar and is therefore progressive with respect to AIME. In other words, a retiree with double the credited lifetime earnings will not necessarily receive double the Social Security benefit. For example, using numbers from 2022, a retiree whose AIME is $1,000 receives a monthly benefit of $900; 30 The monthly earnings that a retiree can expect to receive after normal U.S. retirement age is called the Primary Insurance Amount (PIA). See Bd. of Trs., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2022 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 248 (2022), https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2022/tr2022.pdf [https://perma.cc/​D5L7-YUD3] [hereinafter 2022 Annual Report]. “The PIA is equal to the sum of 90 percent of AIME up to the first bend point, plus 32 percent of AIME above the first bend point up to the second bend point, plus 15 percent of AIME in excess of the second bend point.” Id.; see also supra note 21. The SSA has determined that the first bend point for calculating PIA in 2022 was $1,024 and the second bend point was $6,175. 2022 Annual Report, supra, at 122. Therefore, a retiree whose AIME was $1,000 in 2022 would have their PIA calculated at the 90% factor entirely because it is under the first bend point, $1,024. Hence, (90% × $1,000) = $900. a retiree with an AIME of $2,000 receives a monthly benefit of only $1,234. 31 (90% × $1,024) + (32% × ($2,000 – $1,024)) = $1,234. See supra note 30 for guidance on the variables used to calculate this PIA. Although AIME has doubled, retirement benefits have only increased by 37%.

The progressive nature of Social Security benefits mitigates the regres­sivity of Social Security tax collection. 32 See Jonathan Barry Forman, Promoting Fairness in the Social Security Retirement Program: Partial Integration and a Credit for Dual-Earner Couples, 45 Tax Law. 915, 935 (1992) (“Thus, unlike the rather regressive social security retirement taxes, the social security benefit structure is quite progressive.”); Regina T. Jefferson, “Let Them Eat Cake”: Examining United States Retirement Savings Policy Through the Lens of International Human Rights Principles, 31 Harv. Hum. Rts. J. 63, 105 n.302 (2018) (“It has been argued that the regressive effect of the tax is offset by the progressive effect of the benefit.”). But there is not scholarly consensus on whether the progressivity of the payout structure is sufficient to coun­teract the regressivity of the rest of the program. 33 See Kathryn L. Moore, Redistribution Under the Current Social Security System, 61 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 955, 965 (2000) (“A few commentators . . . suggest that the progressive benefit formula is not sufficient to offset the adverse effect of lower life expectancy.”). For any individual retiree, there is no guarantee that the retiree will obtain the benefits for which they have contributed. A worker who dies the day after retiring may have paid into the Social Security program over the course of their entire working life but will receive zero benefits. Because low-wage earners gen­erally have shorter lifespans, the progressivity of the Social Security payout structure (which is a lifetime benefit) is muted by the shorter payout sched­ule for low-wage earners. 34 See Raj Chetty, Michael Stepner, Sarah Abraham, Shelby Lin, Benjamin Scuderi, Nicholas Turner, Augustin Bergeron & David Cutler, The Association Between Income and Life Expectancy in the United States, 2001–2014, 315 JAMA 1750, 1753 (2016) (finding the gap in life expectancy between the richest and poorest 1% of men and women to be 14.6 years and 10.1 years, respectively).

Discrepancies in life expectancy also disproportionately affect certain racial minorities. According to a recent report by the NIH, the life expectancy for Black Americans and American Indians is approximately four years and six years lower, respectively, than the seventy-nine-year life expectancy for white Americans. 35 Press Release, Life Expectancy in the U.S. Increased Between 2000–2019, but Widespread Gaps Among Racial and Ethnic Groups Exist, NIH (June 16, 2022), https://www.nih.gov/news-events/news-releases/life-expectancy-us-increased-between-2000-2019-widespread-gaps-among-racial-ethnic-groups-exist [https://perma.cc/KF79-DQBF]. Given that full Social Security retirement benefits are available only at age sixty-seven, Black and American Indian retirees with full benefits would receive only seventy percent and fifty-one percent of the retirement benefits of white retirees, respectively. 36 The life expectancy for Asian and Latino populations, however, was 85.7 years and 82.2 years, respectively. Id. Changing the distribution of Social Security tax collection would not alter these discrepancies in benefit payments. But since these racial groups generally earn less than white workers, 37 Off. of Fed. Cont. Compliance Programs, Earnings Disparities by Race and Ethnicity, DOL (July 2020), https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ofccp/about/data/earnings/​race-and-ethnicity [https://perma.cc/9GQD-2Y77] (finding that Black and American Indian workers earn $0.76 and $0.77 per dollar earned by white workers). decreasing the regressivity of Social Security tax collection would reduce the price that these racial groups pay for these truncated benefits.

Focusing on the progressivity of Social Security benefits thus masks the normative shortcomings of the program as a whole. Progressivity should be a feature not only of payouts but also of Social Security tax collection. The following Part discusses how removing the existing wage cap and creating a zero-rate Social Security tax bracket would accomplish that goal.

III. Removing the Social Security Wage Cap to Fund a Zero-Rate Bracket

This Piece proposes removing the wage cap on Social Security taxes and using the additional revenue to create a zero-rate bracket for wages earned. Both wage earners and employers would pay Social Security taxes on all wages paid, not just wages below the wage cap. This exemption would function similarly to how the existing standard deduction currently operates for the federal income tax. Using IRS data, this Piece calculates that the resulting additional revenue raised would fund a zero-rate bracket excluding at least the first $10,000 of wages from Social Security taxes for all earners. 38 See infra notes 52–56 and accompanying text. Taxpayers with more than $10,000 of wages would receive an approximately $1,200 benefit. 39 Exempting $10,000 of wages from Social Security taxes would save taxpayers $1,240 (12.4% × $10,000 = $1,240). Taxpayers with less than $10,000 of wages would pay no Social Security taxes.

Eliminating the wage cap and creating a zero-rate bracket transforms Social Security tax collection from regressive to progressive. 40 See Bruce Jacobs, A Proposed Flexible Personal Exemption for the Federal Income Tax, 18 Stan. L. Rev. 1162, 1164 (1966) (“An exemption increases the rate of progression of the tax rate scale by creating a new first bracket with a zero tax rate. . . . [A] proportional system . . . becomes progressive through the addition of an exemption . . . .”). These determinations of “progressive” and “regressive” are made with respect to wages. By giving all workers some amount of wages that are exempt from tax, the average Social Security tax rate will start at 0% and approach 12.4%, rather than start at 12.4% and approach 0%. 41 Using the proposed exemption of $10,000 and eliminating the wage cap, taxpayers with wages of $10,000, $20,000, $200,000, and $1 million would pay rates of 0%, 6.2%, 11.8%, and 12.3%, respectively. Under the existing regime, these same taxpayers would pay rates of 12.4%, 12.4%, 9.9%, and 2.0%, respectively. Under the existing system, even if the progressivity of Social Security benefit payments mitigates the regressivity of collection, the uncertainty over whether any specific taxpayer will actually receive the benefits for which they have paid means that progressivity is not assured for all taxpayers. As a normative matter, this Piece asserts that Social Security tax collection and benefit provision should both be progressive, rather than just the latter.

Notably, the Social Security benefits that each worker obtains would not change. By explicitly connecting the size of the zero-rate bracket to the revenue raised from eliminating the wage cap, there is no risk that the proposal will jeopardize existing payment obligations to retirees. Wage earners would continue to receive credit based on their AIME, which would continue to be limited by the wage cap (adjusted for inflation) in place for that year. Rather than changing Social Security benefits, the proposal changes the distribution of the Social Security tax burden by shifting payments from low-wage earners to high-wage earners. By keeping elements of Social Security other than tax collection constant, this proposal would be administratively straightforward to implement.

A. Implementation

To create the zero-rate bracket, the IRS would use the additional Social Security taxes collected over the course of the taxable year to pay for an exemption for taxpayers’ wages from that tax year. Employers currently remit employment taxes to the IRS every quarter, with all employment taxes for the previous year generally filed by January 31 following the close of that taxable year. 42 Employment Tax Due Dates, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/businesses/small-businesses-self-employed/employment-tax-due-dates [https://perma.cc/JA5W-7K37] (last updated Oct. 23, 2023). Thus, the revenue available to create the zero-rate bracket for that taxable year will be known prior to processing taxpayers’ income tax returns for that year.

The income tax filings currently submitted by taxpayers already include all the information needed to implement the zero-rate bracket. Taxpayers’ wages are reported on line 1a of Form 1040 and are also documented on the Form W-2 sent by each employer to the IRS. 43 See IRS, Form 1040 (2022), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/f1040.pdf [https://perma.cc/B3JR-33SF]; IRS, Form W-2 (2023), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/​fw2.pdf [https://perma.cc/L7JZ-D7F5]. Taxpayers would, upon filing their income tax return, obtain a refund for the Social Security taxes previously levied on wages within the exemption amount. Assuming an exemption amount of $10,000, workers with wages of $50,000 and $5,000 would receive Social Security tax refunds of approximately $1,200 and $600, respectively. 44 12.4% of $10,000 is $1,240, and 12.4% of $5,000 is $620.

Because the zero-rate bracket is intended to be revenue neutral, there will be a time lag between collecting the tax revenues needed to fund the zero-rate bracket and determining the zero-rate bracket’s exact size. That is, the size of the zero-rate bracket will be known only after the additional revenue generated from lifting the wage cap is known. The IRS, using its internal models, could reasonably approximate the zero-rate bracket’s size and release preliminary estimates as desired. Although precision would decline, giving workers real-time increases to their paychecks might be better than requiring workers to file before obtaining the benefit. Alternatively, the zero-rate bracket could start the year following the elimination of the cap: By using tax revenue from year one to fund the zero-rate bracket in year two, the IRS could release the exact size of the zero-rate bracket well before the end of the taxable year.

Eliminating the wage cap would improve certain aspects of tax administration. The current system can result in an overcollection of Social Security taxes for an employee with multiple employers if the employee’s aggregate wages exceed the wage cap. 45 See Treas. Reg. § 31.6413(a)-1 (2024) (discussing employer repayment and reimbursement of taxes erroneously collected from employees). Because the proposal subjects all wages to Social Security tax and confers the benefits of the zero-rate bracket only upon filing, each employer’s Social Security tax obligations would be independent of the obligations of other employers. Additionally, employers would no longer need to adjust withholding rates during the tax year at the moment their employees’ wages exceed the cap.

B. Estimates of Revenue Generated and Size of the Exemption

Using publicly available IRS data, it is possible to estimate the revenue generated from eliminating the wage cap and approximate the size of the wage exemption that the additional revenue could fund. 46 Eliminating the wage cap would subject all wages to Social Security taxes but would (as is currently done) still exempt other forms of income, such as capital gain. In 2018, for example, $885 billion of Social Security taxes were collected, which represented taxation of 83% of total wages. 47 2022 Annual Report, supra note 30, at 49, 148. Eliminating the wage cap would thus result in approximately $181 billion with which to create a zero-rate bracket. 48 If 100% (instead of just 83%) of wages were taxed, total Social Security tax revenue would increase by 100% divided by 83%, to $1.066 trillion (100% ÷ 83% x $885 billion = $1.066 trillion). Thus, the additional Social Security tax revenue generated by taxing 100% of wages equals $1.066 trillion minus $885 billion = $181 billion. This assumes minimal behavioral changes from eliminating the wage cap. See infra section III.C.1. That same year there were approximately 145 million wage earners, 49 IRS, 2008–2018 Form W-2 Tabulations tbl.3.A, https://www.irs.gov/statistics/soi-tax-stats-individual-information-return-form-w2-statistics [https://perma.cc/U7WM-YBQZ] [hereinafter IRS, Form W-2 Tabulations] (last updated Feb. 15, 2024). meaning that eliminating the wage cap in 2018 could have funded a zero-rate bracket of at least $10,000 across all wage earners, 50 $181 billion ÷ 145 million wage earners ≈ $1,250 per wage earner. This $1,250 for each wage earner could exempt approximately $10,100 of wages per wage earner ($1,250 ÷ 12.4% ≈ $10,100). with taxpayers earning wages of $10,000 or more saving approximately $1,200. 51 In 2018, there were approximately twenty-two million taxpayers with wages less than $10,000, which means that the size of the zero-rate exemption could likely increase since not all wage earners would utilize their pro rata share. See IRS, Form W-2 Tabulations, supra note 49, at tbl.3.A.

IRS data for the years following 2018 are limited, but by making reasonable assumptions, the size of the zero-rate bracket can be estimated for additional years. Table 1 provides estimates of the zero-rate bracket for 2019, 2021, and 2022—years for which the data are less complete. 52 Table 1 uses the OASDI estimated (rather than actual) taxable ratio for 2022 and assumes an annual increase in wage earners of 2% after 2018.

Table 1. Estimated Zero-Rate Wage Tax Bracket Funded by Eliminating the Social Security Wage Cap

Year Taxable Ratio 53 The taxable ratio is the percentage of all wages that is subject to Social Security taxes. See 2023 Annual Report, supra note 14, at 149; 2022 Annual Report, supra note 30, at 148; Bd. of Trs., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2021 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 150 (2021), https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/​2021/tr2021.pdf [https://perma.cc/46LX-8QHB]; Bd. of Trs., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2020 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 146 (2020), https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2020/tr2020.pdf [https://perma.cc/BK57-VASR]; Bd. of Trs., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2019 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 143 (2019), https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2019/​tr2019.pdf [https://perma.cc/3DRG-9URG]; Bd. of Trs., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2018 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 144 (2018), https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2018/tr2018.pdf [https://perma.cc/7LLE-35V8]; Bd. of Trs., Fed. Old-Age & Survivors Ins. & Fed. Disability Ins. Tr. Funds, The 2017 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds 144 (2017), https://www.ssa.gov/oact/tr/2017/tr2017.pdf [https://perma.cc/352M-YZTR]. Total Social Security Tax Contributions (Billions) 54 See 2023 Report, supra note 14, at 168 tbl.VI.A3. Additional Social Security Revenue if No Wage Cap (Billions) 55 Additional Social Security tax revenue = total Social Security tax contributions ÷ taxable ratio – total Social Security tax contributions. See supra note 48. Number of Wage Earners (Millions) 56 IRS, Form W-2 Tabulations, supra note 49, at tbl.3.A; see also Erica York, Summary of the Latest Federal Income Tax Data, 2022 Update, Tax Found. (Jan. 20, 2022), https://taxfoundation.org/data/all/federal/summary-latest-federal-income-tax-data-2022-update [https://perma.cc/7L3W-Q9NA]; Erica York, Summary of the Latest Federal Income Tax Data, 2023 Update, Tax Found. (Jan. 26, 2023), https://taxfoundation.org/​data/all/federal/summary-latest-federal-income-tax-data-2023-update [https://perma.cc/​TY7G-2XVB]; Erica York, Summary of the Latest Federal Income Tax Data, 2024 Update, Tax Found. (Mar. 13, 2024), https://taxfoundation.org/data/all/federal/latest-federal-income-tax-data-2024 [https://perma.cc/5ZGP-GHLV]; Internal Revenue Serv., Data Book 2022, at 6 tbl.3 (2023), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/p55b.pdf [https://perma.cc/​9TRT-W328]. Social Security Taxes Saved per Wage Earner (Dollars) 57 Social Security taxes saved per wage earner = additional Social Security tax revenue ÷ number of wage earners. For an example calculation, see supra note 50. Zero-Rate Bracket Size (Dollars) 58 Zero-rate bracket size = the Social Security taxes saved per wage earner ÷ the Social Security tax rate of 12.4%.
2015 82.6% 794.9 167.4 144.1 1,162 9,371
2016 82.7% 836.2 174.9 144.2 1,213 9,783
2017 83.2% 873.6 176.4 145.8 1,210 9,757
2018 83.0% 885.1 181.3 144.6 1,254 10,111
2019 83.0% 944.5 193.5 148.2 1,305 10,527
2020 82.4% 1,001.3 213.9 157.5 1,358 10,951
2021 81.0% 980.6 230.0 153.6 1,497 12,077
2022 82.3% 1,106.6 238.0 160.6 1,482 11,951

The years following the onset of the COVID-19 pandemic resulted in a significant decrease in the taxable ratio, with the percent of wages below the wage cap falling from 82.2% to 81% between 2020 and 2021. Because the pandemic increased wage inequality, more wages were earned by taxpayers exceeding the wage cap relative to taxpayers below the cap. If the wage cap would have been eliminated during those years (as this Piece proposes), it would have resulted in proportionately more revenue since a higher percentage of wages would have been taxed. Since this revenue would have been used entirely to fund a zero-rate bracket, the result would have been a greater redistribution of money from high-wage earners to low-wage earners as pre-tax wage inequality increased, thereby mitigating (post-tax) the effects of this inequality.

C. Concerns

1. Efficiency. — To the extent that eliminating the wage cap results in significant behavioral changes, these costs might outweigh the normative improvements of the zero-rate bracket. Eliminating the wage cap, however, is not likely to result in significant inefficiencies (i.e., in workers trading leisure for employment). First, increased taxes only induce behavioral changes to the extent that they are salient to taxpayers—that is, to the extent that taxpayers are aware of the increase. 59 Hayes R. Holderness, The Unexpected Role of Tax Salience in State Competition for Businesses, 84 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1091, 1094 (2017) (“Research into tax salience demonstrates that many tax provisions—particularly sales taxes—may be ‘undersalient’ to consumers; consumers ignore these taxes to some degree.”). Social Security taxes (1) are withheld and remitted by employers; (2) only decrease after exceeding approximately $160,000; and (3) are relatively low-rate. 60 See SSA, Contribution and Benefit Base, supra note 2; Kyle D. Logue & Joel Slemrod, Of Coase, Calabresi, and Optimal Tax Liability, 63 Tax L. Rev. 797, 850 (2010). Because Social Security taxes are split between employer and employee, the rate applied to employee wages is 6.2%. See Staff of Joint Comm. on Tax’n, supra note 2, at 19. Social Security taxes are thus considered to be of low salience. 61 See Katherine Pratt, Learning to Live Without Form 1040, 75 Tax Law. 411, 421 (2022) (noting the historically low political salience of payroll taxes).

Second, efficiency costs arising from changed behavior would arise only if employees were able to limit their wage earnings in response to the additional tax. Even though employees might desire to change their behavior, the realities of lucrative employment practically preclude it. The overwhelming majority of employees earning above $160,200 are salaried rather than hourly and would thus be unable to adjust their wages in response to the increased tax. 62 Megan Brenan, Hourly Workers Unhappier Than Salaried on Many Job Aspects, Gallup (Aug. 23, 2017), https://news.gallup.com/poll/216746/hourly-workers-unhappier-salaried-job-aspects.aspx [https://perma.cc/R856-G9UT] (“And while seven in 10 hourly workers have household incomes of less than $75,000, 65% of salaried workers are in households earning $75,000 or more.”). It is difficult, for instance, for a football coach to work fewer hours by forgoing a portion of their salary, even if they wished to do so.

Subjecting all wages to Social Security taxes would also likely have a small effect on labor decisions at the extensive margin, that is, on workers’ decisions to enter the labor force. Unlike the income tax’s notable effect on married spouses’ decisions to obtain paid labor (which subjects the spouse to the marginal tax rate of their partner), eliminating the wage cap would (1) only affect earners making over $160,200, and (2) impose a relatively small tax burden. That is, a worker with the potential to earn $200,000 in wages would likely not forgo those earnings because of the $4,900 in additional Social Security taxes owed. 63 With the wage cap in place, in 2023 a taxpayer with $200,000 in wages pays $19,865 in Social Security taxes (12.4% × $160,200 = $19,865); with no wage cap, this taxpayer pays $24,800 (12.4% × $200,000 = $24,800), a difference of $4,935 ($24,800 – $19,865 = $4,935).

2. Conflicts With Other Changes to Social Security. — The Social Security program is under severe budgetary strain. Under current revenue and benefit predictions, the OASDI trust fund will be exhausted in 2033. 64 CBO, CBO’s 2023 Long-Term Projections for Social Security 2, https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2023-06/59184-SocialSecurity.pdf [https://perma.cc/B46W-SPJ5]. Although the federal government is statutorily obligated to pay benefits to retirees, once the OASDI trust fund is exhausted, these funds must come from other sources, such as the general fund. 65 Id. app. A. If Social Security is intended to be a self-funded program in which benefits to retirees are funded solely by Social Security taxes (plus interest earned and taxes paid on Social Security benefits), significant structural changes to Social Security must be made. 66 Longevity of the OASDI trust fund could be increased by raising Social Security taxes, limiting the benefits of retirees, or increasing the minimum age of retirement.

This Piece’s proposal is not intended to substitute for other, deeper Social Security reforms. Rather, it addresses a specific shortcoming of the existing Social Security program—its regressivity—in an administratively straightforward manner without altering other elements of the program. The proposal’s key features, elimination of the wage cap in conjunction with the creation of a zero-rate bracket, do not preclude other fundamental changes to Social Security that Congress deems necessary. Funding the OASDI trust fund with additional taxes on investment income and business income, for instance (as recently proposed by Senators Bernie Sanders and Elizabeth Warren), can be done in conjunction with this Piece’s proposal. 67 See Press Release, Sen. Bernie Sanders, Sanders, Warren, and Colleagues Introduce Legislation to Expand Social Security by $2,400 a Year and Extend Solvency for 75 Years (June 9, 2022), https://www.sanders.senate.gov/press-releases/news-sanders-warren-and-colleagues-introduce-legislation-to-expand-social-security-by-2400-a-year-and-extend-solvency-for-75-years/ [https://perma.cc/VUS4-G3GC].

3. Unintended Beneficiaries. — This Piece’s proposal is premised on the assumption that redistributing Social Security tax burdens from low-wage earners to high-wage earners is, as a normative matter, preferred. Assuming the declining utility of dollars for higher-earning taxpayers, redistributing a dollar from a taxpayer with wages above $160,200 to a taxpayer earning less than that should result in an increase of overall welfare. For low-wage taxpayers, the savings from the zero-rate bracket would function similarly to the Earned Income Tax Credit, which lifts millions of the working poor out of poverty. 68 Policy Basics: The Earned Income Tax Credit, Ctr. on Budget & Pol’y Priorities, https://www.cbpp.org/research/federal-tax/the-earned-income-tax-credit [https://perma.cc/R3DP-LDM9] (last updated Apr. 28, 2023) (“[I]n 2018[,] the [Earned Income Tax Credit] lifted about 5.6 million people above the poverty line, including nearly 3 million children . . . .”).

By using wages (rather than income or wealth) as the distributional base, however, there is the potential for certain disfavored groups to benefit from the newly formed zero bracket. Part-time workers, including students and the elderly, would also have their first $10,000 of wages exempted from Social Security taxes. But to the extent this is problematic (for example, because low wages don’t accurately reflect their status as the working poor because they are rich retirees or students with significant future earning potential), Congress can easily tailor the zero-rate bracket for groups meeting the desired characteristics. Because the zero-rate bracket will be implemented via income tax returns, Congress could use attributes contained within income tax filing to limit eligibility. Full-time students, taxpayers claimed as dependents, or taxpayers below or above a certain age, for example, could all be precluded from using the exemption if Congress so desired. 69 These taxpayer attributes (and many more) are already part of existing tax return filing. See IRS, Form 1040 (and 1040-SR) Instructions 17–18 (2023), https://www.irs.gov/​pub/irs-pdf/i1040gi.pdf [https://perma.cc/H9QR-LKA4].

Conclusion

By eliminating the wage cap on Social Security taxes and using the additional revenue to subsidize a zero-rate wage bracket, Social Security tax collection can be made progressive without altering the benefits that current retirees receive and future beneficiaries expect. By so doing, roughly ninety-four percent of U.S. taxpayers will pay less in Social Security taxes with no reduction in benefits. 70 See SSA, Population Profile: Taxable Maximum Earners (2021), https://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/population-profiles/tax-max-earners.pdf [https://perma.cc/EX9C-F6HE]. Millions of low-wage taxpayers will receive a credit for Social Security taxes paid, thus expanding Social Security’s promise to provide a social safety net—not just for retirees but for workers in the present as well.