Introduction
Spring 2023 saw the second, third, and fourth largest bank failures in U.S. history. Within six weeks of the first failure, First Republic Bank ($229 billion in assets), Silicon Valley Bank (SVB) ($209 billion), and Signature Bank ($110 billion) were each sold to other banks.
Academic and popular commentary on the 2023 banking crisis has covered its regulatory background,
supervisory shortfalls,
deposit insurance coverage,
cryptocurrency entanglement,
lender of last resort activity,
and more.
The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) responded with a report on deposit insurance reform and an amendment to its 2012 resolution plan rule.
The suite of banking agencies proposed new long-term debt requirements.
But there is a problem yet to be examined: Bank resolution law allocates coordination rights—the right to legally permitted economic coordination
—and it does so on an incoherent basis.
Coordination rights are primarily allocated by antitrust law.
Antitrust favors vertical coordination of economic activity with concentrated control (e.g., within hierarchical firms) rather than horizontal coordination of economic activity between firms or individuals (e.g., cartels or cooperatives).
For example, rideshare drivers who collectively set prices for their services may be illegally conspiring under antitrust law, but it is presumptively legal for Uber or Lyft to set prices for those same rideshare services.
Orthodox accounts justify this pattern by appealing to competition, consumer welfare, and efficiency.
Meanwhile, when commercial enterprises suffer financial distress, they often enter federal bankruptcy.
Bankruptcy triggers an automatic stay, shielding enterprise assets from creditors.
This process favors vertical coordination to some extent: Firms are reorganized, not liquidated (i.e., sold off in pieces to other firms), if they have value as a going concern, and reorganized firms retain decisionmaking
hierarchy.
But banks do not enter bankruptcy.
When a bank fails, it triggers a legal process known as resolution.
Resolution is governed by the Federal Deposit Insurance Act (FDIA).
Although the FDIA does not expressly address how coordination rights should be allocated, in practice, the FDIC prefers to use a resolution method that transfers as much as possible of a failed bank’s balance sheet to another bank, increasing the concentration of coordination rights compared to the status quo ante.
This Note makes two claims. First, bank resolution allocates coordination rights. It decides which parts of the failed bank’s balance sheet it will transfer, to whom it will be transferred, and thus how the post-resolution balance sheet and bank charter will be controlled. The FDIC’s preference for merging a failed bank into another bank privileges hierarchical firm-based coordination for banks, just like antitrust does for nonbank firms. But resolution’s allocation of coordination rights need not follow antitrust’s default allocation. Instead, failed banks could be reconstituted with different firm boundaries or more horizontal intrafirm relations. In other words, a failed bank could be broken up or reorganized as a quasi-worker cooperative—both outcomes that would disperse coordination rights.
Second, resolution’s reflexive concentration of coordination rights is unsupported. While it mirrors antitrust’s allocation, it is not justified by antitrust’s orthodox criteria: competition, consumer welfare, and productive efficiency. Nor is it justified by the rationales underlying banking law, or even by those internal to resolution law. In fact, all these criteria clash with the FDIC’s resolution-by-merger preference.
This reveals that, without good reason, the Agency defers to antitrust’s favor for hierarchical firms.
This Note argues the FDIC can solve this problem by reallocating coordination rights after banks fail. One option is to disperse interfirm coordination rights. The FDIC could draw firm boundaries such that resolution no longer results in one bank where previously there were two. Another option is to disperse intrafirm coordination rights. A new resolution method outlined herein—the intrafirm reallocation transaction (IRT)—could do both, breaking up banks and flattening intrafirm hierarchy as desired. Doing so would better fulfill the criteria of antitrust, banking, and resolution law.
This Note proceeds as follows. Part I explains what coordination rights are, how they are allocated, and why. It also describes the basic structure and aims of banking law and bank resolution. Part II searches for, but struggles to find, justification for the FDIC’s approach to allocating coordination rights in bank resolution. Part III explores alternatives. It shows how the banking agencies could use tools already at their disposal to disperse coordination rights and bring coherence to resolution law. It proposes a new resolution method, IRT, which it argues would best align the practice of bank resolution with the goals of antitrust and banking.